The following points highlight the three main components of the classical theory of employment. The components are: 1. Employment-Output Determination 2. Price Level Determination 3. Interest Rate Determination.

Component # 1. Employment-Output Determination: The Labour Market:

Let us first consider the labour market where we deal with production function in which capital stock is fixed and labour is the variable input.

The aggregate production function is:

Y = f (K̅, L) …(10.2)

ADVERTISEMENTS:

Where, K denotes a constant capital stock and L denotes quantities of variable input, labour.

In the classical model, equilibrium level of output is determined by the employment of labour. The level of output and, hence, the level of employment, is established in the labour market by the demand for and supply of labour.

Assuming a profit-maximizing economy, labour will be demanded up to the point where the revenue earned from selling the total product produced by the marginal unit of labour is equal to the MC of labour. MC of labour is equal to the money wage divided by the marginal product of labour, MPL, i.e.,

MC = W/MPL …(10.3)

ADVERTISEMENTS:

The condition for profit maximization is:

P = MC = W/MPL …(10.4)

Or, P. MPL = W …(10.5)

or, W/P = MPL …(10.6)

ADVERTISEMENTS:

where, W is the money wage, P is the absolute price level, and W/P is the real wage.

We know that the MP curve for labour indicates the firm’s demand for labour. More labour is demanded at a lower wage. Thus, demand for labour depends inversely on real wage. The aggregate demand curve for labour is the horizontal summation of all individual firms’ demand curve for labour. Aggregate labour demand function, shown in equation (10.7), is also inversely related to the real wage rate. That is,

DL = f (W/P) …(10.7)

Like labour demand, aggregate labour supply function also depends on the real wage rate, but in a direct manner. Thus,

SL = g (W/P) …(10.8)

These relationships (equations 10.2, 10.7 and 10.8), together with the equilibrium condition for the labour market determine output, employment and real wage in the classical system.

DL = SL …(10.9)

Equilibrium real wage rate and the equilibrium level of employment are determined at that point where the negative sloping labour demand curve cuts the positive sloping labour supply curve. Once we know the equilibrium level of employment from the aggregate production function we can derive the equilibrium level of output. This is shown in Fig. 10.1.

Labour Market Equilibrium

In the lower panel, aggregate production function has been shown. The intersection between DL and SL curves in the upper part of the figure determines the equilibrium level of employment (Ne) at the equilibrium real wage rate (W/P) f. The equilibrium of the classical labour market is one where everyone willing to work at the real wage (W/P) f is able to find work.

ADVERTISEMENTS:

Incidentally, this is the full employment position, denoted by Ne = Nf. (or decreases) in both money wage and the price level will not change labour supply. The corresponding equilibrium level of output (at the equilibrium level of employment) is Yf. This equilibrium output level is also called full employment output level.

In the classical system, full employment is achieved automatically due to wage-price flexibility. For instance, at a real wage (W/ P)1 there exists a situation of unemployment. Now, this excess supply of labour (AB) will reduce the real wage rate until labour supply is equal to the labour demand. Ultimately, real wage rate will decline to (W/P)f where aggregate labour demand is exactly matched by aggregate labour supply.

It may be added here that the volume of output and employment in the classical system are determined by only the supply side of the market for output. Since the classical model is a supply determined one, it says that the equi-proportionate increases (or decreases) in both money wage and the price level will not change labour supply.

Component # 2. Price Level Determination: The Money Market:

ADVERTISEMENTS:

In this section, we analyse the classical theory of aggregate price level determination. To do this, money market is introduced.

How is the general price level determined? Classicists answered this question in terms of the quantity theory of money which determines aggregate demand, which, in turn, determines the price level. In the classical model, it is assumed that people hold money solely to facilitate transactions. Obviously, such transactions depend on the volume of money income.

So we can say that the total demand for money in an economy is a function of money national income or output. The supply of money and the demand for money jointly establish equilibrium in the money market. The demand for money equation that will be presented here is the Marshallian cash balance version of the quantity theory of money.

It is:

ADVERTISEMENTS:

Md = kPY …(10.10)

Where, Md stands for demand for money, Y the output level, P the price level, and k is the fraction of Y that people want to hold to facilitate transaction. Equation (10.10) states that people hold cash balance since there is a gap between money receipts and expenditures.

The supply of money is fixed as it is supplied by the central bank.

Thus,

MS= M …(10.11)

For equilibrium in the money market,

ADVERTISEMENTS:

M = kPY …(10.12)

Equation (10.12) shows a proportional relationship between money stock and the price level. It is to be remembered here that Y is also fixed due to the existence of full employment in the economy.

Fig. 10.2 represents money market equilibrium where we plot total money stock M on the horizontal axis and the levels of PY on the vertical axis. The vector (OL), the slope of which is (1/k), shows the levels of PY that can be supported by different quantities of money supply. As money supply increases from M1 to M2 the price level rises proportionately from P1 to P2.

Money Market Equilibrium

But money supply does not have any impact on Y which is determined in the real sector and Y is fixed due to full employment. The only way for equilibrium output to change in this classical model can be attributed to a shift in labour demand or labour supply curve.

One essential feature that follows from the classical money market is that money is neutral. This means that changes in money stock affect only absolute prices and money wages proportionately. Real variables—such as, output, level of employment and real wage rate —remain undisturbed following a change in money supply.

Component # 3. Interest Rate Determination: The Goods Market:

ADVERTISEMENTS:

In the classical model, the components of aggregate demand—consumption and investment—determine equilibrium interest rate. Interest rate that guarantees that changes in the particular components of demand do not affect the aggregate level of commodity demand. It may be noted here that the interest rate is a Veal’ variable in the goods market.

The goods market is concerned with the way the fixed output or income is split between saving and consumption. Here we determine equilibrium rate of interest.

Saving implies a choice between present and future consumption. People save in the current period to have larger income or consumption in the future. Of course, such saving then depends on the rate of interest in the classical system and not on income as suggested by J. M. Keynes.

Classicists assumed that saving (S) is an increasing function of the rate of interest (r); that is,

S = f (r) …(10.13)

Investment is defined as the amount of the economy’s investment that means creation of additional capital stock. An investment is something produced that is used to create value in the future. An economy considers a number of capital projects in each time period. It undertakes these projects that yield a rate of return greater than the market rate of interest. Thus, investment depends on the market interest rate.

ADVERTISEMENTS:

On the other hand, investment is an inverse function of the rate of interest; that is,

I = f (r) …(10.14)

The goods market equilibrium is achieved when saving is equal to investment, i.e.,

S = I …(10.15)

A flexible interest rate in the classical system always brings equality between savings and investment. Fig. 10.3 shows how equilibrium rate of interest is determined in the classical model, independent of the monetary sector.

Saving curve (S) and investment curve (I) are equal to each other at point E where the equilibrium volume of saving (Se) is equal to the equilibrium value of investment (Ie). Interest rate is flexible and it adjusts to maintain the equality between saving and investment.

Goods Market Equilibrium

(a) Classical Dichotomy:

One important conclusion from the classical model is the classical dichotomy. This means that the goods market is segmented completely from the remainder of the system. Real sectors cannot influence the monetary sector and, hence, monetary variables. Monetary sector is not concerned with relative prices and real variables.

(b) Policy Implications:

The policy implication of this classical model is that monetary policy alone can influence economic activity. Fiscal policy is an impotent instrument to influence aggregate demand in the classical system.