In this article we will discuss about the substitution and income effect on the budget of a consumer.

Let’s assume that the ordinal utility function of the consumer is

U = f(q1,q2)           [eq. (6.1)]

where q1 and q2 are the quantities of the goods Q1 and Q2, respectively, and U is the ordinal utility number.

ADVERTISEMENTS:

The consumer’s budget constraint can be written as yo = p1q1 + p2q2          [eq. (6.23)]

where yo is his income which is fixed and given, and p1p2 are the given prices of the two goods.

The rational consumer is to maximise U as given by (6.1) subject to the budget constraint (6.23).

In order to find out the conditions for such constrained maximisation, let’s form the relevant Lagrange function:

ADVERTISEMENTS:

V = f (q1,q2) + λ (y° − p1q2 − p2q2)                    [eq. (6.24)]

where λ is the Lagrange multiplier and V is a function of q1 q2 and λ. Also V is identically equal to U for those values of q1 and q2 that satisfy the budget constraint. Constrained maximisation of U would then be the same thing as the simple maximisation of V.

The first- order conditions (FOCs) of the constrained maximisation of U then would be given by:

 

ADVERTISEMENTS:

 

 

 

 

 

 

The quantities purchased by a rational consumer would always satisfy eqns. (6.25)-(6.27). Changes in prices and income will normally alter his purchase plan, but the new quantities (and prices and income) must satisfy the conditions (6.25)-(6.27) if U is to be maximised.

Find the magnitudes of the effects of price and income changes on the consumer’s purchases. To do this, allow all the parameters, viz., p1p2 and y, to vary simultaneously. Also assume that as a result of these autonomous changes, the quantities purchased by the consumer would change by dq1 and dq2.

ADVERTISEMENTS:

Taking total differentials of (6.25)-(6.27), we have:

F11dq1 + f12dq2 – p1dλ = λ dp………..(6.64)

F21dq1 + f22dq2 – p2dλ = λ dp1 ……………(6.65)

−p1dq1 –p2dq2 = − dy + q1dp1 + q2dp2 ……..(6.66)

ADVERTISEMENTS:

Before solving the equation system (6.64)-(6.66), let us note that the terms on the RHS of these equations are constants and they are known to us because these terms involve the autonomous changes and the initial values of different variables.

The array of coefficients on the LHSs of the equation form the following bordered Hessian determinant:

The solutions of the equation system (6.64)-(6.66) obtained with the help of Cramer’s rule, would be:

ADVERTISEMENTS:

Where Dij is the cofactor of the element in the ith row and jth column of D.

Dividing both sides of (6.68) by dp1 and assuming that p2 and y do not change (i.e., dp2 = dy = 0), we have

Now consider a price change that is compensated by an income change that leaves the consumer on his initial indifference curve. In this case, we would get

ADVERTISEMENTS:

Since, in equilibrium, f1/f2 = p1p2, (6.27) gives

Hence from equation (6.66) we obtain

and from (6.68), we obtain

 

 

 

Therefore, (6.70) can now be written:

 

 

ADVERTISEMENTS:

Equation (6.5) is known as the Slutsky equation. Now note that p2,q1 and q2 remaining constant, if there is a rise (fall) in p1 by small one unit of money, the expenditure of the consumer would also rise (fall) by ∂/∂p1 (p1q1 + p2q2) = q1units of money.

This rise (fall) in expenditure would compel the consumer to borrow (save) q1 units of money to maintain his purchase plan (q1, q2). That is why, this rise (fall) in expenditure by q1 units of money is equivalent of a fall (rise) in his (real) income by q1 units of money.

So it may be written as ∂y/∂p1 = -q1 (units of money) and substitute this in (6.75) to obtain the Slutsky equation in different form as given by (6.76) below:

 

 

 

 

Hicks and Slutsky Compensation Demand:

ADVERTISEMENTS:

The quantity ∂q1/∂p1 on the L.H.S of Slutsky equation (6.75) or (6.76) is the slop of the ordinary demand function for Q1, and the first term on the RHS is the slope of the compensated demand function for Q1 (based on the Hicksian compensation criterion).

An alternative compensation criterion (the Slutsky criterion) is that the consumer is provided enough income to purchase his former consumption bundle so that dy = q1dp1 + q2dp2. This is

 

 

 

 

  Which can be substituted for the 1st term on the RHS of (6.75) or (6.76).

At first sight, it might puzzle s that the two rather different compensation schemes led to the same result. However, they only refer to the same derivation, i.e., they only refer to a change in q for an infinitesimally small change n p at a point, and may lead to quite different result for any finite price movement. In other words, for an infinitesimally small change in p1,

 

 

show quite different effect upon q1.

Elasticity Form of the Slutsky Equation (Elasticities of Ordinary and Compensated Demand):

The Slutsky equation may also be expressed in terms of the price and income elasticities.

Multiplying (6.75) by p1/q1 and multiplying the last term on RHS by y/y, we get

 

 

 

 

 

 

Equation (6.78) is the elasticity representation of the Slutsky equation (6.75) or (6.76). It gives that the price-elasticity of the ordinary demand curve (ϵ11) equals the price-elasticity of the compensated demand curve (ξ11) less the corresponding income-elasticity (η1) due to the change in p, multiplied by the proportion of total expenditure on Q,.

Hence, the ordinary demand curve will have a smaller elasticity than the compensated demand curve, considering the negative values of ϵ11 and ξ11 and the positive value of r|,. That is, numerically, the ordi­nary demand curve will have a greater elasticity than the compensated demand curve.

Direct Effects:

The first term on the RHS of (6.75) or (6.76) is the substitution effect (SE) or the rate at which the consumer substitutes Q1 for Q2 when the price of Q1 changes and he moves along a given IC. The second term on the right is the income effect (EE) of a change in p1.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Assume now that only income changes and dp1 = dp2 = 0. Then (6.81) becomes

Since D is positive, the rate of change of MU of income w.r.t. income will have the same sign as -(f11f22 f212). This would be negative if the utility function were strictly concave. How­ever, for ordinal utility functions, only strict quasi-concavity is assumed, and the theory does not predict whether the MU of income is increasing or decreasing with income.

By (6.74), the SE is (D11/D) λ. Since D is positive, D11 = −p22 is negative and X is positive, the SE is clearly negative. This proves that the sign of the SE is always negative and the compensated demand curve is always downward sloping.

A change in real income may cause a reallocation of consumer’s resources even if the relative prices do not change, i.e., if the absolute prices do not change or if they change in the same proportion. The income effect of a change in p1 is (∂y/∂p1).(∂q1/∂y)p’s = const. and it may be of either sign. The final effect of a price change on the purchase of the commodity is thus unknown.

However, an important conclusion can still be derived. The smaller the quantity of Q1, the smaller would be the value of ∂y/∂p1 and the less significant is the income effect. A commodity Q1 is called an inferior good if the consumer’s purchase diminishes as income rises and in- creases as income falls, i.e., ∂q1/∂y if is negative, and this makes the income effect positive (for ∂y/∂p1 is always negative).

In other words, income effect for an inferior good is positive.

A Giffen good is an inferior good with a positive income effect large enough to offset the negative substitution effect and make the price effect, ∂q1/∂p1, positive. This means that if Q1 is a Giffen good, then as p1 falls, q1 also falls.

This may occur if a consumer is sufficiently poor so that a considerable portion of his income is spent on a commodity such as wheat which he needs for his subsistence. Assume that the price of wheat falls.

The consumer who is not very fond of wheat may suddenly discover that his real income has increased substantially as a result of the price fall. He will then buy a smaller quantity of wheat and purchase a more palatable diet with the remainder of his income.

The Slutsky Equation for a Specific Function—an Illustrative Example:

The Slutsky equation can be derived for the specific utility function U = q1q2 (1)

The budget constraint in the general implicit form is: y0 – p1q1 – p2q2 = 0 (2)

Form the Lagrange function V = q1q2 + X (y0 – p1q1 – p2q2) (3)

Setting the partial derivatives equal to zero:

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

From (13) and (14):

 

 

 

Now asume y = 100, p1 = 2, p2 = 5, the equilibrium values of q1 and q2 would be

 

 

 

Now substituting the required values in (15), a numerical answer is obtained

 

 

The meaning of this answer is this. If starting from the initial equilibrium situation, p1 were to change, ceteris paribus, the consumer’s purchase of Q1 would change in the opposite direction at the rate of 12. Units per doller of change in the price of Q1.

The expression –p2λ/2p1 in (13) is the SE, and its value in the present example is p2λ/2p1 = – [(p2/2p1)(y/2p1p2)] = – [(5/2×2)(100/2x2x5)] = – 6.25. The expression – q1/2p1 in (13) is the income effect. Its value is also – 6.25.

Cross Effects:

The Slutsky equation (6.75) and its elasticity form (6.78) may be extend to explain how the demand for one of the goods (Q1) would change because of changes in the price of another good (Q2). From (6.68), we obtain

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Here ϵ12 = price-elasticity of ordinary demand for Q1 w.r.t. p2,

ξ12 = price-elasticity of compensated demand for Q1 w.r.t. p2,

η1 = income-elasticity of demand for Q1

and α2 = proportion of total expenditures spent on Q2.

Therefore, eqn (6.88) gives that the cross-elasticity of ordinary demand for Q1 w.r.t. p2 equals the cross-elasticity of compensated demand for Q1 w.r.t. p2 minus the income-elasticity of demand for Q1 multiplied by the proportion of total expenditures spent on Q2.

Now, the sign of the cross substitution effect is not known in general. Let S12 = D21λ/D denote the substitution effect when the quantity of Q1 is adjusted as a result of variation in the price of Q2. Since D is a symmetric determinant, D12 = D21, and it follows that S12 = S21.

That is, the substitution effect (SE) on Q1 resulting from a change in p2 is the same as the SE on Q2 resulting from a change in p1. This is indeed a remarkable conclusion. The sum of the compensated demand elasticities for Q1 as a result of changes in p1 and p2 is

Here P1D11 + p2D21 equals zero, since it is an expansion of the determinant of (6.64)-(6.66) in terms of alien cofactors, i.e., the cofactors of the elements of the first column are multiplied by the negative of the elements in the last column. From (6.89), we have

ξ11 + ξ12 (6.90)

i.e., the compensated elasticity of demand for Q, w.r.t. p, is equal to the negative of the com­pensated elasticity of demand for Q, w.r.t. p2. Now obtaining another interesting conclusion.

The sum of the negative of the ordinary demand elasticities for Q, caused by changes in p, and p2 as given by (6.78) and (6.88) is:

Therefore, it is obtained that the income-elasticity of demand for a commodity equals the negative of the sum of ordinary price-elasticities of demand for that commodity w.r.t. its own and the other price. In other words, the sum of the own price elasticity, cross price elasticity and income-elasticity of demand for a commodity in a two-good model is equal to zero.

Substitutes and Complements:

Loosely defined, two commodities are substitutes if one of them can be used by the consumer for the other, and they are complements if they are to be used jointly in order to satisfy some particular need. For example, tea and coffee are substitutes and tea and sugar are complements.

However, a more rigorous definition of substitutability and complementarity is provided by the cross-substitution term of the Slutsky equation (6.85), viz., D21λ/D. The goods Q1 and Q2 are substitutes if the substitution effect given by this term is positive, and they are complements if it is negative.

If Q1 and Q2 are substitutes, loosely speaking, and if compensating variations in income keep the consumer on the same indifference curve, an increase in the price of Q2 will induce the consumer to substitute Q1 for Q2. Then (∂p1/∂p2) U = constant would be positive, and it would be negative in the case of complements.

Now, all commodities cannot be complements for each other. Hence, only substitutability can occur in the present two-good case. This can be proved easily. Let’s multiply (6.70) by p1, (6.71) by y, and (6.83) by p2, and add. Then 

The final bracketed term is equal to zero since it is an expansion in terms of alien cofactors as in (6.89).

Therefore:

In (6.92), the substitution effect, S11, for Q1 resulting from changes in p1 is known to be negative. Hence, (6.92) implies that S12 must be positive, and this means, by definition, that Q1 and Q2 are necessarily substitutes.